Outline:

Why this paper deserves our attention:

  1. MAE’s are important in practice.
    • Meaning: People who negotiate the contracts actually care about them.
  2. MAE’s are important in theory.
    • The existence and use of MAE’s have important implications for theory.
  3. Exceptions to MAE’s can tell us a lot about MAE’s themselves.
  4. MAE’s are vastly understudied.
    • As far as I can tell, when this paper gets into a top accounting journal the 380 MAEs in the sample will be all of the MAEs ever used in studies published in those journals.
  5. The authors actually read these contracts.

Three thoughts for a stronger paper:

  1. Theoretical Foundation
  2. Institutional Questions
  3. Empirical Focus

Theoretical Foundation: What is the underlying model?

How do unpredictable and uncontrollable risks affect debt contract design? Theoretically, covenants are mappings from the state space to a set of actions, and they are included and modified to improve contracting efficiency. (Song et al., 2023)

Theoretical Foundation: What is the underlying model?

However, outside events that could not have been anticipated or controlled … can distort these mappings and lead to unintended consequences associated with ex post inefficiencies. … Specifically, we explore how lenders and borrowers use debt contract terms to allocate risks arising from uncontrollable events and whether such terms impact corporate policies. (Song et al., 2023)

Theoretical Foundation: What is the underlying model?

Prior literature provides little empirical evidence about the mechanisms through which debt contracting parties deal with risks generated from exogenous and uncontrollable events. (Song et al., 2023)

Theoretical Foundation: What is the underlying model?

The logic for the inclusion of an MAE clause is simple. Contracts are inherently incomplete and therefore cannot specify a course of action in every future state of the world. As such, an MAE clause can serve as an effective mechanism for lenders to address borrower moral hazard. (Song et al., 2023)

  1. Incomplete contracts are concerned with the efficient allocation of control rights ex-post.
  2. Complete contracts are concerned with aligning incentives ex-ante. This stream of literature is more concerned with moral hazard.

Theoretical Foundation: What is the underlying model?

Incomplete contract theory suggests that contracts are inherently incomplete because the future state is uncertain, and contracts cannot specify the course of action in every future contingency. As we discussed before, the MAE clause serves as a key tool to limit uncertainty for the lender. (Song et al., 2023)

Theoretical Foundation: What is the underlying model?

Incomplete contract theory has a role for performance measurement:

“Accounting information plays an important role within incomplete contract theory because the optimal allocation of control rights is contingent on a contractible signal that reflects the underlying economics of the borrower (Aghion and Bolton [1992], Zender [1991], and Hart and Moore [1988]).” (Christensen et al., 2016)

MAEs do not rely on contractible signals!

Theoretical Foundation: What is the underlying model?

The current theoretical foundation is intuitive: MAEs make sense in an uncertain world.

Theoretical Foundation: Jensen & Meckling & Propability

Jensen and Meckling (1976) argue that post-contractual moral hazard arises because the lender and owner-manager have asymmetric payoff functions, which causes the owner-manager to have a greater incentive to invest in risky projects at the expense of debt holders (i.e., asset substitution). The MAE clause addresses the information asymmetry issue and moral hazard problem by creating a threat of lenders calling default on loans even in the absence of covenant violations, prompting the owner-manager to behave in the lender’s interest and not engage in excessive risk-taking.

(Song et al., 2023 p. 10)

Theoretical Foundation: Jensen & Meckling & Propability

An apt analogy is the way one would play poker on money borrowed at a fixed interest rate, with one’s own liability limited to some very small stake. Fama and Miller (1972, pp. 179-180) also discuss and provide a numerical example of an investment decision which illustrates very nicely the potential inconsistency between the interests of bondholders and stockholders.

(Jensen & Meckling 1976)

Theoretical Foundation: Jensen & Meckling & Propability

Theoretical Foundation: Jensen & Meckling & Propability

Theoretical Foundation: Jensen & Meckling & Probability

Institutional Question: What is the context of the exceptions?

This is the part where the discussant imagines that the authors have infinite time and resources.

Institutional Question: What is the context of the exceptions?

An example from the draft:

“No Material Adverse Effect. Since December 31, 2019, no event or circumstance shall have occurred or be existing that has resulted in, or would reasonably be expected to result in, a Material Adverse Effect; provided that in determining whether a Material Adverse Effect has occurred for purposes of this Section 6.5, current financial and market conditions engendered by the Coronavirus 2019 pandemic (“COVID-19”) shall not be given effect and the direct impacts of COVID-19 on the business, operations or financial condition of Credit Parties that occurred and were disclosed in any Form 10-K, Form 10-Q or Form 8-K filed by the Credit Parties prior to the Closing Date, shall be disregarded.” Source.

Institutional Question: What is the context of the exceptions?

Institutional Question: What is the context of the exceptions?

The Definition of MAE:

Material Adverse Effect” means (a) a material adverse effect on the business, property, results of operations, or financial condition of the Borrower and its Subsidiaries, taken as a whole; (b) material impairment of the ability of the Credit Parties, taken as a whole, to perform their material obligations under any Credit Document; (c) material impairment of the rights of or benefits or remedies available to the Lenders under any Credit Document, taken as a whole; or (d) a material adverse effect on the Collateral or the Liens in favor of the Secured Parties on the Collateral or the priority of such Liens, taken as a whole.

The Second Exclusion:

Institutional Question 1:

Institutional Question 2:

“After loan initiation, the occurrence of an MAE often constitutes an event of default for the borrower, which allows the lender to void the contract and cease its lending obligation (Koff and Singer, 2021).” (Song et al., 2023)

“These renegotiations could occur either in anticipation of future covenant violations (Roberts and Sufi 2009b), or without reference to covenant violations, either through invoking the Material Adverse Change (MAC) clause or through relational contracts that can exist when there are strong ties between lenders and borrowers (Gibbons and Henderson 2012).” (Erkins et al., 2014)

Institutional Question 2:

“Even when the market allowed a free-standing MAE event of default, it was a dangerous default upon which to rely as a lender.”

Institutional Question 2:

Empirical Focus

Minor points